Category Archives: political-economy

The magic legislature

Today freedom and constraint pivot more and more on legislation. People generally realize fully the extraordinary importance of technology in the changes that are taking place in contemporary society. On the other hand, they do not seem to realize to the same extent the parallel changes brought about by legislation, often without any necessary connection with technology. What they appear to realize even less is that the importance of the latter changes in contemporary society depends in its turn on a silent revolution in present-day ideas about the actual function of legislation. In fact, the increasing significance of legislation in almost all the legal systems of the world is probably the most striking feature of our era, besides technological and scientific progress. While in the Anglo-Saxon countries common law and ordinary courts of judicature are constantly losing ground to statutory law and administrative authorities, in the Continental countries civil law is undergoing a parallel process of submersion as a result of the thousands of laws that fill the statute books each year. Only sixty years after the introduction of the German Civil Code and a little more than a century and a half after the introduction of the Code Napoléon the very idea that the law might not be identical with legislation seems odd both to students of law and to laymen.

Legislation appears today to be a quick, rational, and far-reaching remedy against every kind of evil or inconvenience, as compared with, say, judicial decisions, the settlement of disputes by private arbiters, conventions, customs, and similar kinds of spontaneous adjustments on the part of individuals. A fact that almost always goes unnoticed is that a remedy by way of legislation may be too quick to be efficacious, too unpredictably far-reaching to be wholly beneficial, and too directly connected with the contingent views and interests of a handful of people (the legislators), whoever they may be, to be, in fact, a remedy for all concerned. Even when all this is noticed, the criticism is usually directed against particular statutes rather than against legislation as such, and a new remedy is always looked for in “better” statutes instead of in something altogether different from legislation.

The advocates of legislation—or rather, of the notion of legislation as a panacea—justify this way of fully identifying it with law in contemporary society by pointing to the changes continually being brought about by technology. Industrial development, so we are told, brings with it a great many problems that older societies were not equipped to solve with their ideas of law.

I submit that we still lack proof that the many new problems referred to by these advocates of inflated legislation are really brought about by technology or that contemporary society, with its notion of legislation as a panacea, is better equipped to solve them than older societies that never so blatantly identified law with legislation.

The attention of all the advocates of inflated legislation as an allegedly necessary counterpart of scientific and technological progress in contemporary society needs to be drawn to the fact that the development of science and technology, on the one hand, and that of legislation, on the other, are based respectively on two completely different and even contradictory ideas. In fact, the development of science and technology at the beginning of our modern era was made possible precisely because procedures had been adopted that were in full contrast to those that usually result in legislation. Scientific and technical research needed and still needs individual initiative and individual freedom to allow the conclusions and results reached by individuals, possibly against contrary authority, to prevail. Legislation, on the other hand, is the terminal point of a process in which authority always prevails, possibly against individual initiative and freedom. Whereas scientific and technological results are always due to relatively small minorities or particular individuals, often, if not always, in opposition to ignorant or indifferent majorities, legislation, especially today, always reflects the will of a contingent majority within a committee of legislators who are not necessarily more learned or enlightened than the dissenters. Where authorities and majorities prevail, as in legislation, individuals must yield, regardless of whether they are right or wrong.

Another characteristic feature of legislation in contemporary society (apart from a few instances of direct democracy in small political communities like the Swiss Landsgemeinde) is that the legislators are assumed to represent their citizens in the legislative process. Whatever this may mean—and this is what we shall try to discover in the following pages—it is obvious that representation, like legislation, is something altogether extraneous to the procedures adopted for scientific and technological progress. The very idea that a scientist or a technician should be “represented” by other people in the carrying on of scientific or technical research appears as ridiculous as the idea that scientific research should be entrusted, not to particular individuals acting as such even when they collaborate in a team, but to some kind of legislative committee empowered to reach a decision by majority vote.
Nonetheless, a way of reaching decisions that would be rejected out of hand in scientific and technological fields is coming to be adopted more and more as far as law is concerned.

The resulting situation in contemporary society is a kind of schizophrenia, which, far from being denounced, has been hardly noticed so far.

People behave as if their need for individual initiative and individual decision were almost completely satisfied by the fact of their personal access to the benefits of scientific and technological achievements. Strangely enough, their corresponding needs for individual initiative and individual decision in the political and legal spheres seem to be met by ceremonial and almost magical procedures such as elections of “representatives” who are supposed to know by some mysterious inspiration what their constituents really want and to be able to decide accordingly. True, individuals still have, at least in the Western world, the possibility of deciding and acting as individuals in many respects: in trading (at least to a great extent), in speaking, in personal relations, and in many other kinds of social intercourse. However, they seem also to have accepted in principle once and for all a system whereby a handful of people whom they rarely know personally are able to decide what everybody must do, and this within very vaguely defined limits or practically without limits at all.

That the legislators, at least in the West, still refrain from interfering in such fields of individual activity as speaking or choosing one’s marriage partner or wearing a particular style of clothing or traveling usually conceals the raw fact that they actually do have the power to interfere in every one of these fields. But other countries, while already offering a completely different kind of picture, reveal at the same time how much farther the legislators can go in this respect. On the other hand, fewer and fewer people now seem to realize that just as language and fashion are the products of the convergence of spontaneous actions and decisions on the part of a vast number of individuals, so the law too can, in theory, just as well be a product of a similar convergence in other fields.

Bruno Leoni, Freedom & the Law, Introduction

Whither “conservatism”?

I could spend only 24 hours at CPAC because of another commitment, but what I did see told me all I needed to know. Lots of events going on in half-empty rooms of silver-haired attendees. (Not that there’s anything wrong with having silver hair.) The really packed events, including my own talk, were the ones sponsored by Ron Paul’s Campaign for Liberty, and full of young faces. Young Americans for Liberty (not Young Americans for Freedom, naturally) had a huge presence as well. Every single copy of Rollback, my new book, sold during my book signing; it took a full hour of signing at breakneck speed to get to everyone.

We know Ron Paul won the straw poll, of course, with 30% of the vote. Another 7% chose him as their second choice. This is terrible, say the seriosos, for why should Ron Paul’s supporters “hijack” the poll? A better question, never asked, is why the drones competing with him can’t inspire anyone to come vote. And as a friend of mine put it, it says something about the state of conservatism that Ron Paul is viewed as a hijacker of the movement, while Mitt Romney and Donald Rumsfeld are cheered and celebrated.

via CPAC and the Future « LewRockwell.com Blog.

Eugen Rosenstock-Huessy on money and scholarship

Money corrupts. If I have to solicit great foundations for money for my research, then I have to propose something which is already obsolete for me. I know no researcher who in the first moment of a new inspiration could have found the sympathy and approval of the establishment. Whether it’s Galileo, Copernicus, Fichte, or I myself, it’s always the same: the new thought has to break through in battle against the vested interests, the power of the establishment, the conception of squandered money, against money itself—in short, against power of all sorts.

via Risky Business « Biblical Horizons.

Place not your trust in princes

But the issue is not whether you vote Republican or not. The issue is whether you trust Republican. If we do that, then we are a bigger fool than we look.

It is not as though God is making us choose between evils, with us trying to figure out which one is the lesser. Voting Republican is not a venial sin, with a vote for the Democrats being a steaming hot mortal one. The issue on all these things is why and how. Trusting the Democrats is certainly a mortal sin. Trusting the Republicans is a venial one . . . but a sin nonetheless. Christians really ought to knock it off. But trusting perfectionistic third party candidates is obviously the Pathway of Light, upon which, if you walk, no political temptations whatever can behall you. Right? Well, suit yourself, friend. If you never enroll in the class, then nobody ever gets to grade your papers.

via Obama as Charlie Sheen.

To make my own application: the proper response to idolatry is not to tell all the idolators that “you’re doing it wrong,” and insist on campaigning for better idols.

Poverty is known as bad luck

Throughout history, poverty is the normal condition of man. Advances which permit this norm to be exceeded — here and there, now and then — are the work of an extremely small minority, frequently despised, often condemned, and almost always opposed by all right-thinking people. Whenever this tiny minority is kept from creating, or (as sometimes happens) is driven out of a society, the people then slip back into abject poverty.

This is known as “bad luck.”

— Robert Heilein

via White House Startup Initiative Doomed To Fail Because Startups Aren’t The Answer – 24thState.

Obushama’s state of nostalgia

How can we “win the future,” as President Barack Obama exhorted us to do in his 2011 State of the Union address, when our top elected official remains so drearily stuck in the past? And despite the commanding role of what can only be called Sputnik nostalgia in his speech, Obama was not even channeling the distant past in his remarks.

Instead, he served up the equivalent of a microwaved reheating of the sentiments of his immediate predecessor, George W. Bush. That’s some sort of groovy, space-age technological feat, for sure, but we shouldn’t confuse left-over platitudes about cutting wasteful spending on the one hand while ramping up publicly funded “investment” on the other for a healthy meal.

With an unacknowledged debt to the long-running reality show Survivor (“Outwit, Outplay, Outlast”), Obama insisted that we must “out-innovate, out-educate, and out-build the rest of the world.” Which is to say, he sounded exactly like Bush 43, albeit with more open references to China and endless plugs for high-speed rail.

via We Can’t Win the Future By Repeating the Past – Reason Magazine.

If I had written the Larger Catechism: a world without legislatures. Repeal the Modern World!

Q. 191. What do we pray for in the second petition?

A. In the second petition (which is, Thy kingdom come), acknowledging ourselves and all mankind to be by nature under the dominion of sin and Satan, we pray, that the kingdom of sin and Satan may be destroyed, the gospel propagated throughout the world, the Jews called, the fullness of the Gentiles brought in; the church furnished with all gospel officers and ordinances, purged from corruption, countenanced and maintained by the civil magistrate, and that he be freed from the evil institution of the Legislative Assembly; that the ordinances of Christ may be purely dispensed, and made effectual to the converting of those that are yet in their sins, and the confirming, comforting, and building up of those that are already converted: that Christ would rule in our hearts here, and hasten the time of his second coming, and our reigning with him forever: and that he would be pleased so to exercise the kingdom of his power in all the world, as may best conduce to these ends.

(I’m kind of joking of  course.)

Emergency debt, a quick after thought about “Welfare or Debt”

Mark Horne » Blog Archive » Welfare or Debt? Which is ethically preferable.

Just for the record:

In the Bible, financial emergencies are a moral reason for going into debt.

If the emergency is partially due to foolishness, then the pain of the debt will be compounded with feelings of remorse. If there is no remorse then the person in debt will keep being stupid and stop getting credit.

In the people, people in financial emergencies are supposed to get low- or no-interest loans. These are a form of charity and not business. The idea that the poor should not only go into debt but pay higher interest rates is an American perversity. It is a subset of the perversity of accepting unsecured consumer debt as a normal part of the economy.

After all, how do you know that the high interest rate doesn’t encourage a default? Duh.

The advantage of debt is that it teaches a person to do everything possible to avoid such emergencies. He has to work hard to pay back the loan.

But gifts are also an acceptable way to help the poor.

The problem with welfare is that it isn’t charity, but a way that a ruler or regime bribes supporters. (No, I don’t mean welfare recipients, I mean the legions of middle class workers who provide the services).

Nevertheless, if you have to choose between debt and free money, you should choose the free money (though watch out for strings). The fact that doing so “encourages” the welfare state is not a rational consideration. You have no indiidual influence of that kind. It only leads to a world in which only people without scruples got welfare and those with scruples get debt. Since most or all unsecured debt is a government product anyway, I hardly see it as being much of a choice. Again, the state is just outsourcing mastery to a private contractor.

The state loves poor people the way cheetahs love gazelles

I heard this on Dave Ramsey’s show last night and could not believe it. But it didn’t take much googling to find it:

I am the first to admit that I find the whole concept of playing any sort of lottery pretty confusing. When I approach the counter at my local minimart and see all of the various scratch off cards and ticket machines,  I am completely baffled. And I am always afraid that the harried checkout lady – not to mention the customers in line behind me – would be totally irritated if I asked her to stop and explain how it all works to me. So I’ve never played, meaning I’ve never been a winner.

However, here in Tennessee, where I live, my kids will be lottery winners whether or not I ever figure out how to buy a ticket. That’s because our state utilizes state lottery profits to fund the HOPE Scholarship Program, which  pays pretty much the entire cost of tuition (just tuition – not books or housing) for eligible Tennessee students who want to attend any of our state colleges or universities.

The HOPE Scholarship Program has had its hiccups along the way, and there continue to be critics of the idea of having a state lottery at all, but in the past few years, I’ve loved seeing and reading media coverage of all the Tennessee kids who have been able to go to college on the HOPE Scholarship; in many cases, these lottery scholarship recipients are the first members of their family to take their education past high school.  That’s pretty cool.

First thing to remember, the lottery doesn’t just sit there. It is a marketed product. The state of Tennessee advertises that one should play the lottery to win money. It is stupid. There is no excuse for believing the marketing. But the state is actively seducing people to play this game.

Second thing to notice: Do the people who win these scholarships tend to be the people who play the lottery. The lovely aspect of the blog post quoted above is that most such people don’t even understand how the lottery is played. No, they are the social class that gets free money to send their kids to college.

And Third, who does play these games? The poor people. The state actively encourages poor people in bad habits and exploits them to pay for the education of richer and better educated children. It does what it can to perpetuate poverty and benefit from contributing to the poverty of the poor.

Evil.

PS. If you want to know why I used the cheetah-gazelle comparison: go here.